Is the OECD/G20 international corporate tax reform fair?

On October 8th, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) announced that 136 countries have adopted its two-pillar proposal to reform the taxation of multinational enterprises (MNEs).

Pillar One applies to MNEs with sales in excess of $20bn and profits over 10%. It shifts the taxing rights of the next 25% of profits above the 10% threshold to market jurisdictions, that is, to the country where the goods and services of the MNE in question are sold. The measure is thought to apply only to about 100 MNEs, many of them in the highly profitable digital services sector. Pillar Two introduces a minimum tax of 15% for all MNEs with revenues of more than $750m.

Historically, international taxation of MNEs faces two challenges. First, it requires international cooperation to ensure that MNEs cannot game the system and shift their profits to avoid paying taxes. Second, assuming that countries come to agree on a system of cooperation that ensures MNEs are taxed in some way or other, each country will try to maximise its share of the tax revenues.

Overall, the reform certainly seems like good news with regard to the first challenge. It effectively replaces the “race to bottom”, which has often allowed MNEs to pay effective tax rates of close to 0%, by a “race to the middle” around the 15% rate. However, two caveats apply before heralding this as the end of tax avoidance as well as tax competition as we know it.

First, there is a so-called “substance carve-out”, allowing MNEs to pay a lower rate in countries where they have a lot of tangible assets. In other words, if you have a factory with lots of employees in a place, then you can pay less than 15% in that jurisdiction.

This leads to the second worry. Once we are talking about rates below 15%, we are in the territory of rates posted by traditional tax havens such as Ireland’s rate at 12.5%. Is this still cause for celebration, or might the reform be locking in a new low-tax paradigm?

Veneer of inclusion covering up old biases?

When it comes to the second challenge of ensuring a fair and equitable distribution of taxing rights between countries, the reform also raises a number of questions. In particular, there are several indicators that most of the additional revenues projected to be generated by the reform will go to rich, developed countries. This is despite the OECD’s emphasis on its “Inclusive Framework”, which gave developing countries a seat at the table while the reform was developed.

The OECD implicitly acknowledges this problem in its official announcement of the reform, when they state that, for Pillar One’s projected $125bn of additional revenue per year, “developing country revenue gains are expected to be greater than those in more advanced economies, as a proportion of existing revenues.” (my italics) Given the lower fiscal revenues in many developing countries, which are partly due to past exploitation by rich countries through colonialism and the absence of a level-playing field in international economic relations, this leaves open the possibility that developing countries end up with very little in absolute terms.

Specifically, here are several ways in which the new rules are tailored to the needs of rich, OECD countries. Starting with Pillar One, its shift to market jurisdiction by definition favours jurisdictions with large consumer markets. In other words, it favours large, rich countries.

Given the focus of Pillar One on taxing the GAFAs, the highly profitable digital service giants, it is also noteworthy that countries will have to repeal any unilateral digital services taxes they might have adopted in the past in order to be granted access to the additional revenues of Pillar One. It is not clear whether for which countries this will actually mean an improvement.

Moreover, note that for more traditional highly profitable MNEs, the shift to market jurisdiction will tend to hurt developing countries. After all, a significant slice of these MNEs’ profits will now be taxed exclusively in the market jurisdiction and not, as under other possible tax-right-allocation arrangements, at least in part where assets and payroll expenses are located.

Turning to Pillar Two, which is expected to generate $150bn of additional revenue per year, one of the worries from the perspective of poorer countries is that the introduction of the minimum tax will entice MNEs to repatriate some of their capital to where their headquarters are. Since these tend to be in rich countries, some expect the reform to trigger an outflow of capital from poorer countries.

In sum, while the proof of the new international tax pudding will be in the eating, several items on the menu suggest that powerful states have once again pushed through an agreement that favours their interests. This is disappointing, albeit perhaps not all that surprising.

Peter Dietsch

Peter Dietsch is a philosopher and economist, and professor in the Department of Philosophy at the University of Victoria, British Columbia. His research focuses on issues of economic ethics, notably on tax justice, normative dimensions of monetary policy, and on income inequalities. Dietsch is the author of Catching Capital – The Ethics of Tax Competition (Oxford University Press, 2015), co-author of Do Central Banks Serve the People? (Polity Press, 2018), and co-editor of Global Tax Governance – What is Wrong with It and How to Fix It (ECPR Press, 2016). He has published numerous articles and book chapters, and is a regular contributor in the media on debates in his field. In 2017, Dietsch was nominated to the College of New Scholars, Artists and Scientists of the Royal Society of Canada. Dietsch has held visiting positions at the Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin (on a Humboldt fellowship), at the European University Institute in Florence, and at the University of Victoria, British Columbia.

You may also like...

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *